#LyX 2.0 created this file. For more info see http://www.lyx.org/ \lyxformat 413 \begin_document \begin_header \textclass article \begin_preamble \usepackage{graphicx} \usepackage{amsmath} \usepackage{amsfonts} \usepackage{amssymb} %TCIDATA{OutputFilter=latex2.dll} %TCIDATA{CSTFile=LaTeX article (bright).cst} %TCIDATA{Created=Thu Nov 06 21:35:40 2003} %TCIDATA{LastRevised=Tue Nov 11 20:11:57 2003} %TCIDATA{} %TCIDATA{} %TCIDATA{Language=American English} \newtheorem{theorem}{Theorem} \newtheorem{acknowledgement}[theorem]{Acknowledgement} \newtheorem{algorithm}[theorem]{Algorithm} \newtheorem{axiom}[theorem]{Axiom} \newtheorem{case}[theorem]{Case} \newtheorem{claim}[theorem]{Claim} \newtheorem{conclusion}[theorem]{Conclusion} \newtheorem{condition}[theorem]{Condition} \newtheorem{conjecture}[theorem]{Conjecture} \newtheorem{corollary}[theorem]{Corollary} \newtheorem{criterion}[theorem]{Criterion} \newtheorem{definition}[theorem]{Definition} \newtheorem{example}[theorem]{Example} \newtheorem{exercise}[theorem]{Exercise} \newtheorem{lemma}[theorem]{Lemma} \newtheorem{notation}[theorem]{Notation} \newtheorem{problem}[theorem]{Problem} \newtheorem{proposition}[theorem]{Proposition} \newtheorem{remark}[theorem]{Remark} \newtheorem{solution}[theorem]{Solution} \newtheorem{summary}[theorem]{Summary} \newenvironment{proof}[1][Proof]{\textbf{#1.} }{\ \rule{0.5em}{0.5em}} \end_preamble \use_default_options false \maintain_unincluded_children false \language english \language_package default \inputencoding auto \fontencoding global \font_roman default \font_sans default \font_typewriter default \font_default_family default \use_non_tex_fonts false \font_sc false \font_osf false \font_sf_scale 100 \font_tt_scale 100 \graphics default \default_output_format default \output_sync 0 \bibtex_command default \index_command default \paperfontsize 12 \use_hyperref false \papersize default \use_geometry false \use_amsmath 1 \use_esint 0 \use_mhchem 0 \use_mathdots 1 \cite_engine basic \use_bibtopic false \use_indices false \paperorientation portrait \suppress_date false \use_refstyle 0 \index Index \shortcut idx \color #008000 \end_index \secnumdepth 3 \tocdepth 3 \paragraph_separation indent \paragraph_indentation default \quotes_language english \papercolumns 1 \papersides 1 \paperpagestyle default \tracking_changes false \output_changes false \html_math_output 0 \html_css_as_file 0 \html_be_strict false \end_header \begin_body \begin_layout Title First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies \end_layout \begin_layout Author Michael Peters \end_layout \begin_layout Date \begin_inset ERT status collapsed \begin_layout Plain Layout \backslash today{} \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Section Profit Maximization \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Firms transform goods from one thing into another. If there are two goods, \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset , then a firm can transform \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset into \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset into \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset depending on what consumers want. The first figure below represents a simple production technology that the firms might use to do this. \begin_inset Float figure wide false sideways false status open \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Graphics filename firms_fig1.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Caption \begin_layout Plain Layout Production Function \begin_inset CommandInset label LatexCommand label name "fig1" \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard In the figure, the function \begin_inset Formula $y=f\left(x\right)$ \end_inset represents the feasible production choices available to the firm. The horizontal axis measures an arbitrary good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset which could be either an input or an output. When \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset is negative, interpret this to mean that it is being used as an input in the production of some good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset which is measured along the vertical axis. Any good could be an input. For example some firms use labor to produce parts for cars. The parts are an output for that firm. The same parts act as an input for the firm that makes cars. The distinction between inputs and outputs really isn't helpful here. A better idea is to think of a production technology that can transform one good into another. At a point on the production function like \begin_inset Formula $\left(x^{1},y^{1}\right)$ \end_inset , the firm transforms \begin_inset Formula $x^{1}$ \end_inset units of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset into \begin_inset Formula $y^{1}$ \end_inset units of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . At this point, the input \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset is negative and the output \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset is positive. On the other hand, the firm could as easily use \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset as an input ( \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset is negative) and produce \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset as an output as it does at the point \begin_inset Formula $\left(x^{0},y^{0}\right)$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The way that firms are incorporated into things is to assume that firms own all of the endowments of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . They transform \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset to \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset to \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset in whatever way maximizes their profits. Consumers, in turn, own firms. To make things simple, assume there is only a single firm. There will also be two consumers, \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset . Let \begin_inset Formula $\theta$ \end_inset be the proportion of the firm owned by consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset while \begin_inset Formula $\left(1-\theta\right)$ \end_inset is the proportion owned by consumer \begin_inset Formula $2.$ \end_inset Let \begin_inset Formula $\omega_{x}$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $\omega_{y}$ \end_inset be the total amounts of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset that are available to the firm. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Let \begin_inset Formula $z_{x}$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $z_{y}$ \end_inset be the aggregate amounts of \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset that the firm chooses to make available in the economy. If the firm decides that it wants to produce good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset from good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset , meaning that \begin_inset Formula $z_{y}>\omega_{y}$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $z_{x}<\omega_{x}$ \end_inset , then it needs to use up some of its endowment of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and use it in production of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . So, \begin_inset Formula $z_{y}=\omega_{y}+f\left(z_{x}-\omega_{x}\right)$ \end_inset . (Remember that to get \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset out of the production process, we need a negative argument for good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset the way \begin_inset Formula $f$ \end_inset is drawn in Figure \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset .) On the other hand, if it wants to produce good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset (that is \begin_inset Formula $z_{x}>\omega_{x}$ \end_inset ), then it has to use up some of its endowment of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset (so, \begin_inset Formula $z_{y}<\omega_{y}$ \end_inset ). \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Now, imagine drawing a picture as in Figure \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset of the function \begin_inset Formula \begin{equation} z_{y}=\omega_{y}+f\left(z_{x}-\omega_{x}\right)\label{ppf} \end{equation} \end_inset This function is called the \shape italic production possibilities frontier \shape default . It is given as the line segment \begin_inset Formula $CD$ \end_inset in Figure 2. The output of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset varies between \begin_inset Formula $\omega_{y}+f(\omega_{x})$ \end_inset when the amount of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset the firm chooses to produce is 0, to \begin_inset Formula $0$ \end_inset in the case where the firm chooses to produce an output \begin_inset Formula $z$ \end_inset such that \begin_inset Formula $f(z-\omega_{x})+\omega_{y}=0$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Now, suppose that the prices for \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset are given by \begin_inset Formula $p$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset , respectively (I keep using \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset for the price of \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset because it is only the relative price of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset that makes a difference to the firm or the consumers). Whatever the firm chooses to produce it can sell to the consumers at prices \begin_inset Formula $p$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset . So, the profit, or revenue, of the firm is just \begin_inset Formula $pz_{x}+z_{y}$ \end_inset , if it produces \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{x},z_{y}\right)$ \end_inset . An iso-profit locus is a collection of productions that give the same profit. The line segment \begin_inset Formula $AB$ \end_inset in Figure \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset gives part of one such production locus. There are a family of such loci--all of the lines that are parallel to \begin_inset Formula $AB$ \end_inset . If the firm maximizes profits, it picks the highest iso-profit curve that touches its production possibilities frontier. This gives the production choice \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1},z_{2}\right)$ \end_inset in Figure \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Once the firm has produced this output, it distributes its profits back to its shareholders: the fraction \begin_inset Formula $\theta$ \end_inset goes to consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset , and \begin_inset Formula $\left(1-\theta\right)$ \end_inset goes to consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset . Since the consumers use these profits to finance their purchases, both of them would prefer that the firm choose the aggregate production that maximizes its profits since that will always provide them with their highest income for consumption. The income of consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset is \begin_inset Formula $\theta\left(pz_{1}+z_{2}\right)$ \end_inset . This means that the budget line that consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset faces is the one that intersects the \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset -axis at the point \begin_inset Formula $\theta\left(pz_{1}+z_{2}\right)/p$ \end_inset (since that is the maximum quantity of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset he would be able to purchase with that income). \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The outcome at an \emph on arbitrary \emph default (i.e. not equilibrium) price pair \begin_inset Formula $\left(p,1\right)$ \end_inset is given in Figure \begin_inset Formula $2.$ \end_inset \begin_inset Float figure wide false sideways false status open \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Graphics filename firms_fig2.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Caption \begin_layout Plain Layout Out of Equilibrium \begin_inset CommandInset label LatexCommand label name "fig2" \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Each of the two consumers chooses the best point in his or her budget set (which occurs where their indifference curves are tangent to their correspondin g budget lines). The choice by consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset is the consumption bundle \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1},y_{1}\right)$ \end_inset in the figure. Consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset 's choice should be read with respect to the coordinate system that starts at the point \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1},z_{2}\right)$ \end_inset . So, the quantity of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset that consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset wants is given by the horizontal distance between the point \begin_inset Formula $x^{\prime}$ \end_inset and the point \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}$ \end_inset . From this, you can see that the total demand for good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset (which is given by \begin_inset Formula $x_{1}+\left(z_{1}-x^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset ) exceeds the total amount of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset that is produced by the firm. So, the relative price of \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset should rise. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard As the relative price of \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset rises, the family of iso-profit curves faced by the firm will all get steeper. This will cause the firm to choose a profit-maximizing level of output on its production possibilities frontier that involves more \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and less \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . As one might expect, the rising price of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset will cause both consumers to demand a little less \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and a little more \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . Eventually, the increase in supply of \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and the reduction in demand will bring the market to a state of equilibrium. \end_layout \begin_layout Section Competitive (Walrasian) Equilibrium \end_layout \begin_layout Standard A competitive (Walrasian) equilibrium is a pair of consumption choices \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1}^{\ast},y_{1}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset for consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{2}^{\ast},y_{2}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset for consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset , and a production plan \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1}^{\ast},z_{2}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset for the firm such that there is a price \begin_inset Formula $p^{\prime}$ \end_inset for good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset for which the following things are true: \end_layout \begin_layout Enumerate \begin_inset Formula $x_{1}^{\ast}+x_{2}^{\ast}=z_{1}^{\ast}$ \end_inset ; \begin_inset Formula $y_{1}^{\ast}+y_{2}^{\ast}=z_{2}^{\ast}$ \end_inset (the markets clear); \end_layout \begin_layout Enumerate \begin_inset Formula $p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\geq p^{\prime}z_{1}+z_{2}$ \end_inset for any pair \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1},z_{2}\right)$ \end_inset on the firm's production possibilities frontier; and \end_layout \begin_layout Enumerate \begin_inset Formula $u_{1}\left(x_{1}^{\ast},y_{1}^{\ast}\right)\geq u_{1}\left(x_{1},y_{1}\right)$ \end_inset for all \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1},y_{1}\right):p^{\prime}x_{1}+y_{1}\leq\theta\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $u_{2}\left(x_{2}^{\ast},y_{2}^{\ast}\right)\geq u_{2}\left(x_{2},y_{2}\right)$ \end_inset for all \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{2},y_{2}\right):p^{\prime}x_{2}+y_{2}\leq\left(1-\theta\right)\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard You can see what happens after the price of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset rises (to \begin_inset Formula $p^{\prime}$ \end_inset ) in Figure \begin_inset Formula $3.$ \end_inset \begin_inset Float figure wide false sideways false status open \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Graphics filename firms_fig3.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Caption \begin_layout Plain Layout Equilibrium \begin_inset CommandInset label LatexCommand label name "fig3" \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard In the picture, consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset now has income \begin_inset Formula $\theta\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset which he uses to buy \begin_inset Formula $x_{1}^{\ast}$ \end_inset units of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset . Now, consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset chooses to buy \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}^{\ast}-x_{1}^{\ast}$ \end_inset units of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset , and the markets clear. \end_layout \begin_layout Section First Welfare Theorem \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The \emph on first welfare theorem \emph default is one of the most important contributions of classical microeconomic theory. It says that no \emph on feasible \emph default allocation exists in which all consumers are better off than they are in the competitive equilibrium. This is similar to the argument that we made for an exchange economy: consumer indifference curves must be tangent at any equilibrium. However, production adds another wrinkle. It might be true that both consumers could be made better off if the firm would just behave in a different fashion and pick some production plan that doesn't necessarily maximize profits. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Actually we can argue that if we take any pair of consumption bundles where \emph on both \emph default consumers are better off, then there can be no production plan that makes this feasible. To see this, suppose that \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1}^{\prime},y_{1}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{2}^{\prime},y_{2}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset are consumption bundles such that \begin_inset Formula \[ u_{1}\left(x_{1}^{\prime},y_{1}^{\prime}\right)>u_{1}\left(x_{1}^{\ast},y_{1}^{\ast}\right) \] \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula \[ u_{2}\left(x_{2}^{\prime},y_{2}^{\prime}\right)>u_{2}\left(x_{1}^{\ast},y_{2}^{\ast}\right) \] \end_inset One observation is immediate. Whenever this is true, it must be that \begin_inset Formula \[ p^{\prime}x_{1}^{\prime}+y_{1}^{\prime}>\theta\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\right) \] \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula \[ p^{\prime}x_{2}^{\prime}+y_{2}^{\prime}>\left(1-\theta\right)\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\right) \] \end_inset The reason for this is that consumers choose the very best consumption bundles that they can afford with their income. If they could have afforded \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1}^{\prime}.y_{1}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{2}^{\prime},y_{2}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset , then they certainly would have chosen them. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Now, if the firm is maximizing its profits \begin_inset Formula \[ p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\ast}+z_{2}^{\ast}\geq p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\prime}+z_{2}^{\prime} \] \end_inset for any \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1}^{\prime},z_{2}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset along the firm's production possibilities frontier. So, it must be that \begin_inset Formula \[ p^{\prime}x_{1}^{\prime}+y_{1}^{\prime}>\theta\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\prime}+z_{2}^{\prime}\right) \] \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula \[ p^{\prime}x_{2}^{\prime}+y_{2}^{\prime}>\left(1-\theta\right)\left(p^{\prime}z_{1}^{\prime}+z_{2}^{\prime}\right) \] \end_inset Then, if we add these two inequalities together, we get \begin_inset Formula \[ p^{\prime}\left(x_{1}^{\prime}+x_{2}^{\prime}-z_{1}^{\prime}\right)+\left(y_{1}^{\prime}+y_{2}^{\prime}-z_{2}^{\prime}\right)>0 \] \end_inset If prices are positive, then at least one of the two expressions \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1}^{\prime}+x_{2}^{\prime}-z_{1}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $\left(y_{1}^{\prime}+y_{2}^{\prime}-z_{2}^{\prime}\right)$ \end_inset are strictly positive, which means the firm simply can't produce enough to supply what consumers want. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard So, it is good for firms to maximize profits in two senses. First, if the firm were to propose some alternate production plan which didn't involve profit maximization, both consumers would expect their income to fall (notice that this is partly because they don't expect the change in production plan to have any effect on prices). So, the shareholders of the firm would unanimously vote against such a change. Second, even if the firm could change its production plan, and even if prices do change, the alternate plan can't possibly make both consumers better off. Notice that when we make either of these arguments, we don't value profits of firms for their own sake. We are only concerned with the utility of consumers. \end_layout \begin_layout Section Distribution \end_layout \begin_layout Standard One thing you should notice about this entire construction is that firms don't, in any sense, create wealth or goods. The ability to create is embedded in the production possibilities frontier which is taken as a given. \begin_inset Foot status open \begin_layout Plain Layout The traditional theory of the firm has nothing to say about where this productio n possibilities frontier comes from. This makes it pretty useless in thinking about things like economic development , or economic growth. \end_layout \end_inset All firms do is decide how to allocate this wealth. Many potential ways to choose among alternate production plans exist. For example, the government could choose the entire production plan. This was the model used in centrally-planned economies like the old Soviet Union. Alternatively, one could imagine a mixture of private, profit-maximizing firms and publicly-regulated companies, similar to what happens in most Western economies. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Profit maximization isn't necessarily good for everyone. To see this, consider the following example in which one of the consumers (say consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset ) simply has an endowment of the goods \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset but does not own shares. The other, consumer 2, owns a firm that can transform \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset into \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset (and conversely)-- possibly by buying some of the endowment of consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset . The firm that is owned by consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset starts with some endowment of goods. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard To begin, suppose that the government declares that the firm is not allowed to produce anything and that it simply has to give its endowment to consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset who can use the endowment to finance the best consumption plan possible. Restrictions like this are pretty common. An example might be a zoning restriction that prevents a homeowner from turning her house into an apartment building, or a farm owner who is not allowed to build housing on his farm land. A possible outcome is shown in Figure \begin_inset CommandInset ref LatexCommand ref reference "fig4" \end_inset \begin_inset Formula $.$ \end_inset \begin_inset Float figure wide false sideways false status open \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Graphics filename firms_fig4.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Caption \begin_layout Plain Layout Distribution \begin_inset CommandInset label LatexCommand label name "fig4" \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard In Figure \begin_inset Formula $4$ \end_inset , consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset starts with an endowment equal to \begin_inset Formula $\left(\omega_{x}^{1},\omega_{y}^{1}\right)$ \end_inset . Consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset owns no shares of the firm. The firm owns an endowment \begin_inset Formula $\left(\omega_{x}^{2},\omega_{y}^{2}\right)$ \end_inset and this firm is in turn owned by consumer \begin_inset Formula $2.$ \end_inset If the firm simply offers its endowment for sale on the market then the feasible set of trades is given by the wide flat box whose corners are at the origin, and at the point where the line segment \begin_inset Formula $A^{\prime}B^{\prime}$ \end_inset intersects the production possibilities frontier. Prices adjust until the relative price of \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset is \begin_inset Formula $p^{\prime}$ \end_inset . In the associated exchange equilibrium, consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset receives the allocation \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1}^{\ast},y_{1}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset . Consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset 's indifference curve is tangent to this point, so conditional on the production decision of the firm, no allocation can make both consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset and consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset better off. Notice that in this equilibrium, consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset is selling some of his endowment of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset in order to acquire good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset . Of course, consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset is doing the opposite: selling off the good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset that the firm provides in order to acquire good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The iso-profit curves faced by the firm are all parallel straight lines whose slopes are equal to \begin_inset Formula $-p^{\prime}.$ \end_inset Plotting the aggregate endowment point on the production possibilities frontier shows that simply selling off the endowment does not maximize the firm's profits. The iso-profit line (with slope \begin_inset Formula $-p$ \end_inset ) is flatter than the production possibilities frontier. Consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset will do better if the firm alters its production plan to produce some additiona l \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset from the endowment of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset because this will increase the income that consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset takes to the market. To put is in a slightly different way, observe that the steep production possibilities curve means that consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset can acquire good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset much more cheaply by having the firm produce it than she can by buying it from consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard If the firm is now free to raise its output of \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset , it will create an excess supply of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset that will make \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset 's relative price fall, or make \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset 's relative price rise. Both these things are bad for consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset who is buying \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and selling \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . When markets finally clear, the relative price of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset will level off at \begin_inset Formula $p$ \end_inset , and consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset will end up at point \begin_inset Formula $E$ \end_inset where he is much worse off than he was in the original equilibrium. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Oddly enough, this new equilibrium is \emph on Pareto optimal \emph default . There is no way to make \emph on both of the consumers \emph default better off by changing the firm's production plan. How does one reconcile this with the fact that consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset was so much better off in the original equilibrium? \end_layout \begin_layout Standard One possible answer that may have occurred to you is that the original equilibri um is also Pareto optimal. This is partly right and partly wrong. The absolute value of the slope of the production possibilities curve, at the point where the iso-profit curve \begin_inset Formula $A^{\prime}B^{\prime}$ \end_inset crosses it, is called the \emph on marginal rate of transformation \emph default between \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset . If you think of using one small unit \begin_inset Formula $dx$ \end_inset of \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset as the input, then the slope gives the amount of \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset that you get back out for each such unit. At the point \begin_inset Formula $\left(x_{1}^{\ast},y_{1}^{\ast}\right)$ \end_inset where the indifference curves for the consumers are tangent, the indifference curves both have slope \begin_inset Formula $-p^{\prime}$ \end_inset . The absolute value of this is less than the marginal rate of transformation along the production possibilities frontier. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard So, what is the slope of consumers \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset 's indifference curve? His marginal rate of substitution is the amount of good \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset you would need to give him to compensate him when you take away a little ( \begin_inset Formula $dx$ \end_inset ) of his good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset . Consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset 's indifference curve is tangent at this point. That means if you do a tiny transfer of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset , say \begin_inset Formula $dx$ \end_inset , from consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset to consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset , and consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset compensates \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset by giving him \begin_inset Formula $dy$ \end_inset in exchange, where \begin_inset Formula $dy$ \end_inset is \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset 's (and \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset 's) marginal rate of substitution, neither \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset are any better off. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Instead of transferring good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset from consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset to consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset , suppose that \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset transfers a tiny bit of good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset to \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset who uses it to produce additional \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset using the production function. The production possibilities frontier is steeper than \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset 's indifference curve, so this will give \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset more than enough output to pay \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset his marginal rate of substitution and maintain his utility. But then, all the residual output will be left over for consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset to enjoy. In other words, when the production possibilities frontier is steeper than both consumer's indifference curves, 2 can take a little of \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset 's good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset and use it to produce \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset , which he uses to pay \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset back for the good \begin_inset Formula $x$ \end_inset . Then, \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset will have some output left over for himself. The endowment point can't be Pareto optimal. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard On the other hand, if Pareto optimality is the only objective, it can be achieved at the initial endowment point simply by moving along the contract curve until the consumers' marginal rates of substitution are equal to the marginal rate of transformation in production. Figure 5 shows how this might be accomplished. \begin_inset Float figure wide false sideways false status open \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Graphics filename firms_fig5.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Plain Layout \begin_inset Caption \begin_layout Plain Layout An Alternative \begin_inset CommandInset label LatexCommand label name "fig5" \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Notice that at the point \begin_inset Formula $E^{\prime}$ \end_inset in Figure \begin_inset Formula $5$ \end_inset , the indifference curves are both tangent and have the same slope as the production possibilities curve at the endowment point. So, everything is Pareto optimal. This might be achieved by having the government regulate the firm's output choice, tax away some of the firm's profit (a tax on dividends or capital gains) and then redistribute the proceeds to consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset . Consumer \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset will love this alternative plan, and consumer \begin_inset Formula $2$ \end_inset will hate it, but it will produce a Pareto optimal outcome. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Pareto optimality is a perfectly sensible objective for economic policy to try to accomplish. Profit maximization by firms is one way to achieve this, but you need to remember that it is a means to a goal, not a goal in itself. You should also try to remember, as Figure \begin_inset Formula $5$ \end_inset illustrates, that there are alternative ways of achieving Pareto optimality. Different methods lead to different distributional consequences - so, even though all consumers will agree that they want the outcome to be Pareto optimal, they may sensibly disagree about how this is accomplished. \end_layout \end_body \end_document