#LyX 2.1 created this file. For more info see http://www.lyx.org/ \lyxformat 474 \begin_document \begin_header \textclass amsart \use_default_options true \begin_modules theorems-ams eqs-within-sections figs-within-sections \end_modules \maintain_unincluded_children false \language english \language_package default \inputencoding default \fontencoding global \font_roman default \font_sans default \font_typewriter default \font_math auto \font_default_family default \use_non_tex_fonts false \font_sc false \font_osf false \font_sf_scale 100 \font_tt_scale 100 \graphics default \default_output_format default \output_sync 0 \bibtex_command default \index_command default \paperfontsize default \spacing single \use_hyperref false \papersize default \use_geometry false \use_package amsmath 1 \use_package amssymb 1 \use_package cancel 1 \use_package esint 1 \use_package mathdots 0 \use_package mathtools 1 \use_package mhchem 1 \use_package stackrel 1 \use_package stmaryrd 1 \use_package undertilde 1 \cite_engine basic \cite_engine_type default \biblio_style plain \use_bibtopic false \use_indices false \paperorientation portrait \suppress_date false \justification true \use_refstyle 0 \index Index \shortcut idx \color #008000 \end_index \secnumdepth 3 \tocdepth 3 \paragraph_separation indent \paragraph_indentation default \quotes_language english \papercolumns 1 \papersides 1 \paperpagestyle default \tracking_changes false \output_changes false \html_math_output 0 \html_css_as_file 0 \html_be_strict false \end_header \begin_body \begin_layout Title Finance \end_layout \begin_layout Author Michael Peters \end_layout \begin_layout Thanks \begin_inset ERT status open \begin_layout Plain Layout \backslash today{} \end_layout \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The edgeworth box provides a nice way to think about trade in markets. The kind of market for which that theory probably best applies is financial markets. This note explains how to use the edgeworth box to understand asset pricing. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The approach begins with two traders and two goods. The first step to understanding all this is to think about income in different states as representing two distinct goods. Insurance is an example in which this is true. An insurance policy only pays you money if you have an accident. Money means a lot more to you when you have an accident than when you don't, which is why you might be willing to give up money when you don't have an accident by paying an insurance premium in order to get it when you do have an accident. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Lets start with a simple Walrasian equilibrium in a two good exchange economy similar described with an Edgeworth box. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard \align center \begin_inset Graphics filename /home/peters/files/docs/book/finance/finance_fig1.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The figure describes a Walrasian equilibrium for an economy with two goods. Trader 1 starts at the origin, and has quantity \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset of good 1 and \begin_inset Formula $y-d$ \end_inset of good 2. He makes a trade with trader to in which he exchanges \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}$ \end_inset units of good 1 for \begin_inset Formula $z_{2}$ \end_inset units of good 2. This takes both of them to the point where the indifference curves are tangent so that the allocation is pareto optimal. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard In finance, we want to interpret the goods by imagining that there is an as yet unrealized event, say a recession. Trader 1 has income \begin_inset Formula $y$ \end_inset if there is no recession, but has much lower income \begin_inset Formula $y-d$ \end_inset if there is. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Before it is known whether or not the recession occurs, there is a market in which two 'securities' can be traded. The first security, \begin_inset Formula $a$ \end_inset , pays \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset dollar if and only if there is no recession. Security \begin_inset Formula $b$ \end_inset pays \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset dollar if and only if there \size normal \emph on is \emph default a recession. We imagine that the way the event contingent transfer occurs is that trader 1 sells \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}$ \end_inset unit of security \begin_inset Formula $a$ \end_inset , for which he receives total revenue \begin_inset Formula $qz_{1}$ \end_inset . He uses the revenue to buy \begin_inset Formula $z_{2}=qz_{1}$ \end_inset units of security \begin_inset Formula $b$ \end_inset from individual 2. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The, once the event is realized, when a recession occurs, trader 2, since she has sold \begin_inset Formula $z_{2}$ \end_inset units of security \begin_inset Formula $b$ \end_inset , is obliged to pay \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset \begin_inset Formula $z_{2}$ \end_inset dollars. If the recession doesn't occur, then \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset is on the hook since he is the one who sold off \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}$ \end_inset units of security \begin_inset Formula $a$ \end_inset . \end_layout \begin_layout Standard There is a second way to look at this tradeoff. From \begin_inset Formula $1$ \end_inset 's perspective, what he does is to plan how much income he would like to have in each of the two events. His plan is to arrange it so that he has income \begin_inset Formula $c_{n}$ \end_inset if there is no recession and \begin_inset Formula $c_{a}$ \end_inset when there is a recession. To accomplish this, he realizes that he has to purchase and sell assets that will force him to pay \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}$ \end_inset if there is no recession, but will leave him with a payment of \begin_inset Formula $z_{2}$ \end_inset when a recession occurs. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard The way he might do this is to take the matrix of asset returns, given by \begin_inset Formula \[ \left[\begin{array}{cc} 1 & 0\\ 0 & 1 \end{array}\right] \] \end_inset and post multiply it by his portfolio \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1},z_{2}\right)$ \end_inset viewed as a column vector to get the payments that he wants. In other words, he would solve the equation \begin_inset Formula \[ \left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-y\\ c_{a}-y+d \end{array}\right]=\left[\begin{array}{cc} 1 & 0\\ 0 & 1 \end{array}\right]\cdot\left[\begin{array}{c} z_{1}\\ z_{2} \end{array}\right] \] \end_inset which obviously has the solution described above. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard As we are working here with a Walrasian equilibrium, trader 2 is happy with the trade she makes, which is to receive \begin_inset Formula $c_{n}-y$ \end_inset when there is no recession, but to pay \begin_inset Formula $c_{a}-y+d$ \end_inset when there is. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard At this point, we could ask what the prices of the securities have to be so that the market for them clears. To see this, we just consider the Walrasian equilibrium first and imagine that the price of good 1 is \begin_inset Formula $q$ \end_inset while the price of good 2 is \begin_inset Formula $1.$ \end_inset The bundle \begin_inset Formula $\left(c_{n},c_{a}\right)$ \end_inset has cost \begin_inset Formula $qc_{n}+c_{a}$ \end_inset which is equal to \begin_inset Formula $qy+y-d$ \end_inset since it is a Walrasian equilibrium. Then of course, \begin_inset Formula $q\left(c_{n}-y\right)+\left(c_{a}-y+d\right)=0$ \end_inset , from which it is obvious that the price of asset \begin_inset Formula $a$ \end_inset has to be \begin_inset Formula $q$ \end_inset to get this to work. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard We could express this as a problem is computing a security price \begin_inset Formula $\rho$ \end_inset for asset 1 such that \begin_inset Formula \[ \rho z_{1}+z_{2}=\rho\left(c_{n}-y\right)+\left(c_{a}-y+d\right)=0 \] \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula \[ \rho=-\frac{c_{a}-y+d}{c_{n}-y}=q. \] \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard So far this is pretty obvious, so lets enrich the model to make it look more like a stock market. Suppose that our two traders are entrepreneurs. Each of them has an inheritance \begin_inset Formula $\omega$ \end_inset that they have no matter what. But each has a start up venture they are running. The start up of trader 1 gives profits \begin_inset Formula $\pi_{a1}>0$ \end_inset if there is no recession and \begin_inset Formula $\pi_{a2}<0$ \end_inset if there is. Trader 2 has another start up that does well in a recession. Her company earns \begin_inset Formula $\pi_{b1}<0$ \end_inset if there is no recession, but make a profit \begin_inset Formula $\pi_{b2}$ \end_inset if there is a recession. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Now lets take the first figure above, and just relabel it so that it coincides with this new information. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard \align center \begin_inset Graphics filename /home/peters/files/docs/book/finance/finance_fig2.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Here is the same diagram with the trades labeled. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard \align center \begin_inset Graphics filename /home/peters/files/docs/book/finance/finance_fig3.eps \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Now we can imitate what we did before. We'll let \begin_inset Formula $q=\frac{c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2}}{c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}}$ \end_inset be the price ratio that seems to support the Walrasian equilibrium. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard To support this outcome, trader 1 has to buy a portfolio \begin_inset Formula $\left(z_{1},z_{2}\right).$ \end_inset As the assets are now profits in start up companies, the portfolio has to satisfy the following matrix equation: \begin_inset Formula \[ \left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\\ c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2} \end{array}\right]=\left[\begin{array}{cc} \pi_{a_{1}} & \pi_{b1}\\ \pi_{a2} & \pi_{b_{2}} \end{array}\right]\cdot\left[\begin{array}{c} z_{1}\\ z_{2} \end{array}\right] \] \end_inset It is straightforward how we should do this, pre multiply both sides of the equation by the inverse matrix \begin_inset Formula \[ \left[\begin{array}{cc} \pi_{a_{1}} & \pi_{b1}\\ \pi_{a2} & \pi_{b_{2}} \end{array}\right]^{-1}\left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\\ c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2} \end{array}\right]= \] \end_inset \begin_inset Formula \[ \frac{1}{\pi_{a1}\pi_{b2}-\pi_{b1}\pi_{a_{2}}}\left[\begin{array}{cc} \pi_{b2} & -\pi_{b1}\\ -\pi_{a2} & \pi_{a_{1}} \end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\\ c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2} \end{array}\right]=\left[\begin{array}{c} z_{1}\\ z_{2} \end{array}\right] \] \end_inset So we can compute the portfolio rather easily. The interpretation is just as before. Trader 1 is going to sell off \begin_inset Formula $z_{1}$ \end_inset of the shares in his venture and use the proceeds to purchase shares in the venture being run by trader 2. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard All we have left to do at this point is to try to figure out how the shares of the two ventures should be priced. Lets use the convention that the shares in venture 2 should have a price 1, so that all we need to figure out is what the corresponding relative price \begin_inset Formula $\rho$ \end_inset should be of the shares in venture 1. \end_layout \begin_layout Standard Now it is just computation. We have to have \begin_inset Formula $\rho z_{1}+z_{2}=0$ \end_inset , which means \begin_inset Formula \[ \frac{1}{\pi_{a1}\pi_{b2}-\pi_{b1}\pi_{a_{2}}}\left[\begin{array}{cc} \rho & 1\end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{cc} \pi_{b2} & -\pi_{b1}\\ -\pi_{a2} & \pi_{a_{1}} \end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\\ c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2} \end{array}\right]=0 \] \end_inset If we want to solve this, we can obviously forget about the constant \begin_inset Formula $\frac{1}{\pi_{a1}\pi_{b2}-\pi_{b1}\pi_{a_{2}}}$ \end_inset and solve \begin_inset Formula \[ \left[\begin{array}{cc} \rho & 1\end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{cc} \pi_{b2} & -\pi_{b1}\\ -\pi_{a2} & \pi_{a_{1}} \end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\\ c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2} \end{array}\right]=0 \] \end_inset instead. This gives first \begin_inset Formula \[ \left[\begin{array}{cc} \rho\pi_{b2}-\pi_{a2} & \pi_{a1}-\rho\pi_{b1}\end{array}\right]\left[\begin{array}{c} c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\\ c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2} \end{array}\right]=0 \] \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula \[ \left(\rho\pi_{b2}-\pi_{a2}\right)\left(c_{n}-\omega-\pi_{a1}\right)+\left(\pi_{a1}-\rho\pi_{b1}\right)\left(c_{a}-\omega-\pi_{a2}\right)=0. \] \end_inset From the Walrasian equilibrium, this is \begin_inset Formula \[ \left(\rho\pi_{b2}-\pi_{a2}\right)=-q\left(\pi_{a1}-\rho\pi_{b1}\right) \] \end_inset or \begin_inset Formula \[ \rho=-\frac{q\pi_{a1}-\pi_{a_{2}}}{\pi_{b2}-q\pi_{b1}}. \] \end_inset \end_layout \begin_layout Standard So this formula describes the basics of asset pricing. To compute the value of an asset, you need to know a couple of things. The first of which is the returns on other assets - even though we are trying to find the relative price of asset \begin_inset Formula $a$ \end_inset we have to know \begin_inset Formula $\pi_{b1}$ \end_inset and \begin_inset Formula $\pi_{b2}$ \end_inset to do that. Second, we need to know the state price \begin_inset Formula $q$ \end_inset , which we can compute by solving for a Walrasian equilibrium. \end_layout \end_body \end_document